menu
Framing the New Inequality featured image
L’inégalité des revenus

Les prochaines élections fédérales détermineront l'orientation des politiques en matière d'inégalité des revenus

The Politics of Income Redistribution in Canada

Keith Banting and John Myles 21 mai 2015

Résumé

Ce chapitre examine les enjeux politiques dans le dĂ©bat sur les nouvelles inĂ©galitĂ©s de revenu. Le Canada s’efforce actuellement de dĂ©finir ou d’« encadrer » l’Ă©volution de ce phĂ©nomène et les tensions sociales qui en dĂ©coulent. Que se passe-t-il au juste ? Et pourquoi ? S’agit-il d’un problème de politiques publiques ? Ces questions reçoivent des rĂ©ponses divergentes, susceptibles de rĂ©orienter le dĂ©bat en cours.

Trois cadres ont retenu l’attention : le cadre historique antipauvretĂ©, le cadre assez rĂ©cent du centile le plus riche de la population et le cadre encore contestĂ© de la classe moyenne. Si chacun vise une redistribution significative des revenus, les formes proposĂ©es varient. Mais quelle que soit l’option retenue, la mise en Ĺ“uvre d’une meilleure redistribution se heurtera Ă  de fortes contraintes, notamment aux normes d’intervention Ă©tablies et Ă  la reprĂ©sentation inĂ©gale des intĂ©rĂŞts Ă©conomiques dans notre système politique. Seul le processus Ă©lectoral pourrait mobiliser les forces qui remettent en question ces normes et intĂ©rĂŞts Ă©tablis. Et seuls les Ă©lecteurs de la classe moyenne seraient en mesure de favoriser un changement de cap, selon qu’ils jugent leurs intĂ©rĂŞts compatibles avec ceux des groupes Ă  revenu faible ou alors ceux Ă  revenu Ă©levĂ©.

Auteurs

Keith Banting est titulaire de la Chaire de recherche en politiques publiques de l’UniversitĂ© Queen’s, et professeur au dĂ©partement d’Ă©tudes politiques et Ă  la School of Policy Studies de Queen’s. Ses nombreuses publications portent sur les politiques sociales, notamment l’incidence de la diversitĂ© ethnique sur la solidaritĂ© sociale. Il a coĂ©crit son plus rĂ©cent livre, Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics (2013), avec John Myles.

John Myles est professeur Ă©mĂ©rite de sociologie et chercheur principal associĂ© Ă  la School of Public Policy and Governance de l’UniversitĂ© de Toronto. Jusqu’en 2011, il a Ă©tĂ© titulaire de la Chaire de recherche du Canada sur le fondement social des politiques publiques. Il a Ă©crit abondamment sur les politiques comparatives de l’État-providence et les questions de redistribution du revenu au Canada. Il a coĂ©crit son plus rĂ©cent livre, Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics (2013), avec Keith Banting.

Ce chapitre fait partie de l’ouvrage collectif Income Inequality: The Canadian Story. Il est le fruit de deux années de collaboration entre l’IRPP et le Réseau canadien de chercheurs dans le domaine du marché du travail et des compétences (RCCMTC). Pas moins de 27 éminents experts y analysent les tendances en matière d’inégalité au Canada, les facteurs ayant dicté l’augmentation des inégalités depuis le début des années 1980 et le rôle que doivent jouer les politiques publiques pour remédier au problème.

This chapter was published in Income Inequality: The Canadian Story. It is the result of a two-year collaboration between the IRPP and the Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network (CLRSN). As part of this project, twenty-seven leading economists and experts in the field examine income inequality trends in Canada, the factors contributing to its marked increase since the early 1980s, and the role of policy in addressing the problem.


In Canada, redistributive politics has been stuck for more than a decade. Actual redistribution1 has faded significantly. According to the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), in the 1980s and early 1990s government taxes and transfers reduced the gap the most between rich and poor in Canada, Denmark, Finland and Sweden (OECD 2011). By the late 1990s and early 2000s, Canada had joined Switzerland and the United States as the countries with the smallest redistributive impact. The redistributive fade in Canada between the mid-1990s and the mid-2000s was among the most dramatic in the OECD world. Moreover, Canada is on the leading edge of the 99/1 phenomenon, with the OECD estimating that the top 1 percent of Canada’s income earners have captured 37 percent of total income growth over the past three decades (OECD 2014).

Until now, however, political reaction has been muted. To be sure, there has been considerable commentary about growing inequality, sparked by the Occupy Movement of 2011 and the dramatic rise in the incomes of the top 1percent. But the buzz has not translated into serious political engagement by governments or the leaders of major political parties. As a country, Canada has not focused on policies to narrow the yawning gap that is opening up between the affluent and the rest.

As the country approaches the 2015 federal election, however, the debate is heating up. The political parties are jostling with one another to find ways to respond to growing public unease about inequality, with each unveiling new policy proposals. But the language of “inequality” itself is at best a minor theme in these debates. Party leaders all present their proposals as designed to “help families.” Moreover, their proposals vary markedly in their redistributive -implications, with the differences reflecting sharply divergent assumptions about what is happening in Canada and the nature of the problems we face.

In effect, the country is engaged in a vigorous struggle to define or “frame” the new inequality and the social stresses it brings in its wake. What is happening? Why is it happening? Is it a policy problem? There are multiple answers to these questions. And the conflicting interpretations pervade debates in the media and legislatures, as well as the proposals that parties present to the electorate. The result is considerable flux in policy debates.

These disagreements are partially the result of competing interpretations of the data before us. At a deeper level, however, the multiple interpretations reflect a political struggle over the future of the redistributive role of the Canadian state. Which policy frame comes to dominate debates – to be sanctified as “conventional wisdom” and to shape future policy development – is a profoundly political question, and changes in such established ways of thinking about social problems depend on shifts in politics.

We argue that a new inequality frame – especially one emphasizing redistribution – confronts serious constraints in the form of the conventional wisdom of policy elites and the unequal representation of economic interests in our politics. However, in contrast to the reconfiguration of interest-group coalitions that has shaped policy reform in some European countries (Avdagic, Rhodes and Visser 2011; Häusermann 2010; Thelen 2014), we emphasize the primacy of political parties and the realignment of electoral coalitions in guiding policy development in Canada.

Assessing the electoral prospects of a new inequality frame is complicated by the recent realignment of Canada’s party system. The centrist brokerage politics responsible for social policy initiatives in the past was swept away – temporarily, at least – in the 2000s by the polarization of both the party system and the electorate. Whether or not this realignment endures, the prospects for electoral momentum behind a new inequality frame are uncertain at best. In the short term, the prospects for continued flux in our debates and in our policies are real.

The Empirics of the New Inequality

The surge in inequality in the past several decades is “new” in a double sense. First, as Paul Starr writes, “According to the received wisdom of the mid-twentieth century, the recent increase in inequality was not supposed to happen” (2014, 33). Among policy elites whose lives spanned the postwar decades, both theory and practice suggested that the concentration of income and wealth at the top associated with earlier eras was over (Kuznets 1955). Disparities of income and wealth remained, of course, but with the rising importance of human capital and the evolution of political democracy toward more inclusive social rights, the peaks of income and wealth concentration were supposed to be a thing of the past. Not so, it turns out. Second, although in retrospect we can now track the rise in inequality back to the late 1970s, good evidence is just over a decade old.

Although there is a broad academic consensus on the facts of the matter, the inequality surge has generated vigorous political debates about how the “facts” should be read and about their import. It is possible to tell different stories about the new inequality by adopting different data sources or time periods, or by focusing on trends in different parts of the income distribution. The resulting disagreement is one that we stylize here as a debate between the “inequality Cassandra” and the “inequality denier.”

With the suppression of the mandatory long-form census in 2011, Canada is left with two main sources of data on family incomes. The best known are Statistics Canada’s national income surveys – the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) and the Survey of Labour and Income Dynamics (SLID) – which date back to the 1960s. They are useful for many things, but because they have comparatively small samples and are not mandatory, they are not very useful for telling us what is going on among small populations such as top-income earners. For the top 1 percent or even the top decile, we have to turn to administrative tax records (the Longitudinal Administrative Databank) that have been used widely for only about a decade.

The normal starting point is the SCF/SLID series. On the basis of the GINI coefficient, the most commonly used measure of income inequality, the SCF/SLID series yields three main conclusions (see Heisz, and Heisz and Murphy, in this volume) about trends in income inequality.

  • Inequality in market incomes from earnings and investments began rising in the early 1980s, surged ahead over the entire 1990s and then levelled off in the 2000s. The GINI coefficient rose from .37 to .44, a huge change in a measure that is difficult to move.
  • Strikingly, transfers and taxes completely offset this rise until roughly 1994. Until that point, the welfare state was doing its job, and there was little change in disposable-income inequality (that is, in income after taxes and transfers).
  • In the mid-1990s, aided and abetted by cuts to employment insurance benefits and social assistance, the tax-and-transfer system “ran out of gas”– it could no longer keep up with rising inequality in market incomes. The result was a sharp rise in inequality in post-tax and post-transfer incomes, and the GINI index for disposable incomes rose from about .29 to .32 by the end of the decade. Since then, inequality levels, as measured by the SCF/SLID series, have remained essentially flat.

Banting-Myles fig1

As figure 1 indicates, if we look at trends over the full three decades, and especially since 1990, our inequality Cassandra has a case to make: inequality in market incomes has risen a lot since 1980, and since the mid-1990s the welfare state has not taken up the slack. But our inequality denier can urge us to stop worrying, emphasizing that the growth in inequality has abated and that the level has stabilized since 2000.

The debate revives again, however, if we focus attention on different points in the income distribution. Our Cassandra reminds us that the SCF/SLID data miss most of the action above the 90th percentile, and that we need to turn to taxation data. The story there, as told by Thomas Lemieux and Craig Riddell (in this volume), is a simple one: virtually all of the income gains in Canada between 1982 and 2010 have gone to the top 10 percent. Statistics Canada data also indicate that the share of total income received by the top 1 percent of tax filers rose from approximately 7 percent in the mid-1980s to peak at 12 percent in 2006-07, then fell back somewhat to 10.6 percent in 2010 following the financial crisis of 2008-09 (see figure 2).2

Banting-Myles fig2

Does this end debate? Not quite. The denier counters by pointing to the other end of the income distribution: trends in the poverty rate. The denier also might refer at this point to the conventional view articulated by Feldstein (1998) that, although governments should worry about rising poverty, concern about the rich getting richer when no one else is being made worse off violates the Pareto principle and is mainly due to envy. Here you get a choice between two series published by Statistics Canada, the traditional low income cut-off (LICO) that has been in use since the 1960s or the low-income measure (LIM) of more recent vintage (see Heisz, in this volume). Both series use living standards in the “middle” of the distribution to benchmark poverty, but they answer somewhat different questions. The LICO uses a fixed reference point (adjusted for inflation) – in this case, 1992 – and asks if living standards at the bottom have changed since that time. By that standard, Canada’s poverty rate has been falling since 1996, and the downward trend continued through the 2000s, reaching its lowest point ever (about 9 percent) in 2010. The LIM, in contrast, uses a moving reference point, and simply asks what percentage of the population has incomes less than 50 percent of the median income in the year of observation. By that benchmark, the poverty rate has remained more or less constant at about 13 percent over the past two decades. This historical constancy in the LIM simply means that incomes at the bottom and in the middle of the distribution have been moving largely in tandem. So, as figure 3 indicates, poverty is either stable or declining – take your pick.

Banting-Myles fig3

Our inequality Cassandra battles back by shifting attention to yet another part of the income distribution. Although the poor might not be getting poorer, the new inequality is generating strains in the middle of the distribution, especially among the lower-middle class. Technological change is altering the labour market, hollowing out the middle (Beach 2014), and the wage and salary growth of middle-income earners has been tepid, at best, for a generation. Hence, the sense of anxiety triggered by economic insecurity is creeping up the income scale.

Nonetheless, our inequality denier is not to be outdone, and replies that, compared with the middle class elsewhere, Canadian middle-income earners are doing very well. Indeed, in 2014, a New York Times study created a stir by indicating that the standard of living of the middle class is higher in Canada than in the United States (Leonhardt and Quealy 2014). The rise in incomes in Canada since the early 2000s does compare favourably with the stagnation of middle incomes in the United States. Cassandra points out, however, that Canadian data have been skewed by the resource boom in Alberta and Saskatchewan and that the middle class in other parts of the country is in as much trouble as in other countries, including the United States (Corak 2014).

In short, although there might be considerable consensus among the experts in this volume on the basic story of inequality, there is sufficient complexity in the data to allow for competing interpretations or framings of what growing inequality “really” means. Moreover, consensus on the empirics is rarely sufficient to trigger political action. The “facts” must first be filtered through policy frames–– both the causal and normative beliefs used to interpret the facts – and the selection of policy frames depends, in turn, on the political actors who are able to dominate the framing process.

Contending Policy Frames: Poverty and the New Inequality

Social problems do not fall from the sky fully formed. They are social -constructions in the sense that economic and social phenomena need to be interpreted, defined or “framed.” As March and Simon observed long ago, “Choice is always exercised with respect to a limited, approximate, simplified ”˜model’ of the situation” (1958, 139). Policy frames provide that simplified model, defining what is really happening (the “facts”), why or how it is happening (a causal narrative) and associated views on whether what is happening is good or bad (a normative position). Such frames also define, implicitly or explicitly, the range of relevant policy options and, thereby, the political stakes involved. If a particular frame comes to dominate political debates, it tends to become institutionalized or embedded, informing official interpretations of social trends and guiding policy changes.

Our analysis is based on a simple model of the politics of framing. Changes in economic or social conditions trigger the advocacy of new policy frames – new ways of interpreting the environment in which policy-makers operate. The adoption of a new frame by the policy community is relatively straightforward if it happens to be consistent with established policy approaches and instruments and with the concerns of strongly organized economic interests. If it is not, heavier political ammunition is required. In some countries, coalitions of weaker interest groups sometimes challenge established approaches. But in pluralist democracies such as Canada and the United States, electoral politics typically is the force that generates the political energy required to overturn conventional wisdom in policy circles and challenge the preferences of strongly entrenched interests.3 The realignment of US electoral politics engineered by the Republican Party under Ronald Reagan stands as a striking example.

The battle to frame problems is especially important in the case of unexpected developments. Surprises produce uncertainty and flux when the “correct” interpretation of the situation seems up for grabs and political parties and policy elites are at a loss as to what, if anything, to do. As noted earlier, the new inequality represents such a surprise.

Like nature, politics abhors a vacuum. The result has been the proliferation of frames, and our current controversies are driven by competition between a historical frame and several recent challengers.

Inequality and the antipoverty frame

Throughout much of the twentieth century, the framing of inequality in Canada was constructed around an evolving “antipoverty” rhetoric. With the rise of an affluent working class in the years after the Second World War, the mass poverty of the past was apparently eliminated. So attention turned to the minority who could be identified statistically as the “poor.” As Starr notes about discourse in the United States, “So closely was inequality identified with poverty that the two terms were often used as if they were interchangeable” (2014, 33). In Canada, as well, redistributive politics became antipoverty politics, and redistributive policies were constructed within an antipoverty frame.

The antipoverty frame has deep historical roots in the British Poor Law tradition, and carries well-established definitions, causal narratives, normative stances and policy debates. First, it defines the population in need of redistribution as a statistical minority, set apart from the majority who are not impoverished. Second, over the years, this framing has generated a ritualized debate about the causal mechanisms that produce poverty, which tends to polarize around two positions: the bad behaviour of the poor themselves versus misfortune and bad luck often attributed to structural causes. These causal beliefs, in turn, contribute to sharp normative distinctions between the “deserving” poor (widows, orphans, the elderly) and the “undeserving” (young employable adults). Finally, the frame comes loaded with an enduring debate about policy responses between those favouring social programs highly targeted at the poor for efficiency reasons and those favouring more inclusive, universalistic programs for reasons of political effectiveness (Korpi and Palme 1998).

The framing of redistributive policy in continental Europe was rather different. Dating back to Bismarck’s Germany of the 1880s and the papal encyclical Rerum Novarum of 1891, redistributive policy was framed in terms of the “workers’ problem.” The “working class” produced by industrial capitalism was, of course, a much more inclusive slice of the population than the “poor,” and could not easily be ignored. The issue became how to integrate a modern industrial working class increasingly given to supporting socialist political movements. The response was a social insurance welfare state providing “workers” with old age pensions and unemployment and sickness insurance. It was not until the 1980s that the poverty problem (the “socially excluded,” in European parlance) became part of the European debate.

Canada, like most countries, pursued the social insurance model from the 1940s to the 1970s, introducing unemployment insurance, old age pensions and health insurance. Motivated by the mass dislocation of the 1930s and guided by the Marsh report (1943) and similar blueprints, the postwar generation built a social infrastructure designed to meet the needs not just of the “poor” but of Canadians generally. To be sure, these general programs helped the poorest most, redistributing resources and life chances down the income scale, but that was not their primary purpose. The social role of the state was also to protect the incomes of the population as a whole, and to help Canadians meet their health care and education needs. Not surprisingly, perhaps, these programs also came to be seen as instruments of territorial integration, knitting together a vast country otherwise divided by language and region.

It did not take long, however, for Canadian discourse to gravitate back to a focus on the poor. In the late 1960s, Canada “rediscovered poverty.” Statistics Canada introduced a new measure of “poverty,” the LICO, which policy agencies and activists have monitored carefully ever since. Every surge in the LICO was the occasion for demands for a new political offensive by antipoverty and other groups that claimed to speak for the disadvantaged. Government departments concerned with the elderly, children, the disabled and lone parents routinely monitored LICO rates among their client populations. This trajectory peaked in 1989, when Parliament unanimously adopted a motion committing Canada to abolish child poverty by the year 2000.

Policy followed. In the 1970s, the federal and provincial governments launched the Social Security Review, which debated a major restructuring of social programs to target benefits more tightly at the poor. In the 1980s, the Macdonald Royal Commission on the economy added its voice, recommending a sweeping move away from universal transfer programs to a single, integrated, income-tested benefit. Such proposals for radical restructuring failed. But the antipoverty focus guided incremental change in the decades that followed, a process perhaps best symbolized at the federal level by the long, slow evolution from universal family allowances to income-targeted child benefits. Policy design in this period was guided by what is known as the “negative income tax” (NIT) model, sometimes referred to as a guaranteed income. A similar pattern prevailed in all the Anglo-Saxon countries (Myles and Pierson 1997); the Earned Income Tax Credit in the United States, the Family Tax Credit in Australia, the Child Tax Credit in the United Kingdom and, in Canada, the National Child Benefit and, most recently, the Working Income Tax Benefit are examples.

In recent decades, Canada updated its poverty frame by embracing the European metaphor of “social inclusion.” Here the focus was less on the poor generally and more on groups that face multiple barriers to entry into the mainstream of society, especially into the labour force: newly arrived immigrants, single mothers, Aboriginal peoples, people with disabilities. This discourse highlighted the needs of excluded groups, but remained firmly within an antipoverty framework. The primary indicator of exclusion was a long-term poverty rate considerably higher than among the population as a whole, and the discourse implicitly deflected attention away from inequality among full-time workers in the paid labour force.

The dominance of the historic antipoverty frame, however, is being challenged by the new, rising inequality, which is accompanied by stable or declining poverty rates, depending on how it is measured. The rich are getting richer, but the poor are not getting poorer. To be sure, the “poverty problem” has not gone away. Canada continues to tolerate poverty rates well above international norms, and there are many who insist that policy-makers should still give priority to the problems of the poor and the socially excluded. Yet a primary focus on poverty no longer fully captures the strains generated by rising inequality. In effect, the antipoverty frame and the policy tools it has generated have run out of political gas.4 The unbalanced growth of Canadian incomes in recent decades has created an opening for alternative, competing frames.

Inequality and the 99/1 frame

The big success of the 2011 Occupy Movement was to change the narrative from a poverty story to an inequality story with the “99/1” metaphor. Moreover, the 99/1 frame prompts a reevaluation of history. In Capitalism in the Twenty-First Century, Piketty (2014) demonstrates that, if we zoom out in time, we see the postwar lows in income inequality from the 1950s to the 1980s as a historical anomaly, accounted for by two world wars and the Great Depression. According to Piketty, we are now back to business as usual in the capitalist world: back to the high concentration of income and wealth of the Gilded Age, la Belle Époque and the Roaring Twenties. Canadian experience seems consistent with this view (see figure 2). The income share of the top 1 percent peaked in Canada at 18 percent around 1930, fell rapidly to about 10 percent in 1945 and continued to drift down to about 8 percent by 1985. Since then, it has since risen to about 12 percent (Veall 2012).

Because the 99/1 frame is new, opinion has not yet crystallized into routinized positions. Indeed, current debates offer a cacophony of causal narratives. Most interpretations point to changing economic and/or political institutions to account for escalating executive salaries (see Keister 2014 for a review). Accounts that focus on economic institutions highlight changing organizational norms and procedures for setting executives’ salaries, enabling them to use their market power to extract rents from the rest of us. More politically oriented accounts emphasize the growing access of economic elites to national political institutions and the rising political influence of high-income groups (Hacker and Pierson 2010). A different approach shifts attention away from economic and political institutions, and blames deeper dynamics inherent in capitalism generally. Piketty (2014), for example, argues that the “natural” returns to capital will outstrip returns to labour into the foreseeable future, and he is not alone in making such an assumption.5

These diverse causal stories mingle with varied normative stances and policy prescriptions. Many conservatives insist that the rise of the 1 percent is a benign phenomenon, the sign of an innovative economy, and warn that efforts to reverse the trajectory can only damage the efficient functioning of markets. Many reformers reply that high levels of inequality have serious negative impacts: slower economic growth, diminished equality of opportunity and declining responsiveness of democratic governments to the electorate as a whole (Stiglitz 2012). The most obvious policy response for those worried about the dramatic rise of the 1 percent is higher taxes on high incomes and wealth.

On its own, however, the 99/1 image has political limits. Although the image clearly has captured considerable public attention, an exclusive focus on the 1 percent is unlikely to move the dial on national income inequality very much, since the 1 percent are, by definition, few in number and employ accountants well schooled in the skills of tax avoidance. A broader sweep of the tax brush undoubtedly would be needed to produce consequential change, which points to a second competing framing of the new inequality.

Inequality and the middle-class frame

The poverty frame and the 1 percent frame highlight the extremes of the income distribution. What about everyone else, the often vaguely defined “middle class”? Politicians always pay attention to middle-income voters, and certainly the most intense debate about the new inequality focuses on its implications for the middle mass that makes up the majority of the electorate.6

The imagery of a mass middle class emerged during the postwar decades, subsuming a now high-wage working class able to purchase suburban homes, automobiles, appliances, vacations and other accoutrements of a “middle-class” lifestyle unavailable to most families in the prewar decades. The production of a mass middle class became a defining feature of Western capitalist democracies, viewed as both a source of their social stability and, during the Cold War, a symbol of their superiority to the economic models of eastern Europe.7 For a while at least, policy elites believed the ups and downs of the capitalist business cycle that wrought recurring periods of mass unemployment could be managed through macroeconomic policy. Expanding welfare states gave citizens stability over the life course through enhanced protection against childhood poverty, unemployment, sickness and old age.

During the 1980s, the threat of the erosion of the middle class began to emerge as an alternative to the antipoverty frame, especially in the United States (Bluestone and Harrison 1982). A combination of globalization and postindustrialism, it was argued, was destroying traditional “middle-class” jobs in manufacturing, replacing them with a world polarized between well-paid knowledge workers in high-end services and low-paid “McJobs” in the personal services industries. In the 1988 US presidential election, Michael Dukakis (Democrat) and George H.W. Bush (Republican) campaigned with their respective experts and their contrary claims about the fate of the US middle class. Bush won, and during the economic recovery of the 1990s, the topic faded from view. Since the implosion of the US economy and housing market in 2008, the fate of the middle class once again has become front and centre in US political debates.

Though less prominent, because less severe, the erosion of the Canadian middle class is also now on the political agenda. Since 1970, there has been a marked decline in the proportion of workers receiving middle-class earnings, and a corresponding marked increase in the proportions receiving higher and lower earnings (Beach 2014). Average real incomes have been comparatively stagnant for decades, and the relative earnings and savings of younger adults (those under age 35) have fallen in the past 30 years with no significant policy response. Fortin et al. sum up the impact of greater inequality in the following terms: “The young and the poorly educated have borne the brunt of these forces, but significant numbers of those previously in the middle and lower middle of the occupational skill and wage distribution have also been adversely affected” (2012, 133). Of course, given the regional nature of the Canadian economy, there has been considerable variation in the trends across the country. The middle class in Ontario and Quebec has been in the economic doldrums for several decades, while both middle- and lower-income workers in western Canada flourished during the recent oil boom (Corak 2014; Fortin and Lemieux forthcoming, summarized in this volume; Green and Townsend 2013).

The causal narratives associated with the middle-class framing of inequality are even more complex than those associated with the 99/1 frame. The factors at work range from transformations in the labour market associated with postindustrialism, technological change and globalization to demographic shifts (such as declining fertility, slowing population growth and population aging) and changes in marital behaviour and family structure (rising divorce rates, greater marital homogamy). Policy changes have also mattered, with retrenchment, especially in the 1990s, weakening the redistributive impact of the tax-and-transfer system. There is no single “smoking gun” at which analysts and policy-makers can point their collective finger (Banting and Myles 2013).

The policy implications of the middle-class framing of inequality are also much broader than an exclusive focus on the top 1 percent or the poor. Here, the role of social policy is not simply to help a group at the bottom or to tax those at the top more heavily, but to respond to the strains confronting the majority of Canadian families in the middle and bottom thirds of the income distribution. In many ways, the policy implications of this frame represent a case of back to the future – back to the broad-based policy approaches that guided the postwar generation. The contemporary version of this agenda is potentially lengthy: child benefits, child care and early childhood education, protection for those in nonstandard forms of employment, compensating for the erosion in occupational benefits, eldercare, just to name a few.

Although the agenda resembles that of the postwar era, the current situation is very different. Then, policy-makers were enjoying the growing revenue streams produced by the postwar economic boom. Now, they contend with a world of slow economic growth and a politically driven decline in government revenue. Then, they were creating institutions where few existed. Now, they must find the revenue both to maintain established institutions (hospitals, old age pensions) and to finance new social innovations in eldercare, public transport and early childhood education. All this represents a classic case of the “double–funding” problem: the old trains need to be kept running at the same time that track is being laid for new, high-speed rail.

Shifting to a middle-class framing of inequality, however, also reframes the debate about public revenue and taxation. Raising taxes on the top third of the income distribution certainly would generate more revenue than targeting the top 1 percent – revenue that could be used to reduce taxes on those in the -lower-middle and bottom half of the distribution, or to enhance transfers and other programs designed to raise their incomes. Indeed, it is difficult to imagine any serious effort by governments to rebalance the income distribution in the long run in the absence of additional revenue and more taxation.

Of course, not all policies advanced in the name of the middle class reflect an inequality frame. The implication of the besieged “middle-class” framing of growing inequality is an alignment of the economic interests of the “middle” with the bottom, rather than with those at the top. But many policies advanced in the name of the middle class actually assist upper-income earners even more, and are likely to exacerbate inequality. As we shall see below, the politics of inequality depends mightily on whether middle-income voters align themselves with the interests of upper-income groups or of lower-income groups when responding to policy choices.

There are thus multiple ways of thinking about the new inequality, each with different policy implications. The historic antipoverty frame no longer captures critical social stresses, but as yet no other framing has come to dominate debates. The LICO might not be as central today as in the past, but, as David Good (2013, 210) observes, no single institution in government is responsible for monitoring or managing the GINI coefficient. The result is a somewhat unfocused debate, a flux in policy ideas. Determining which frame comes to dominate and is embedded in policy is a profoundly political process. It is time to ask whether political forces might generate a new dominant framing of the new inequality in Canada.

The Politics of a New Policy Frame

Politics is a three-front war. It is conducted through three simultaneous battles: a battle of ideas, a battle of organized interests and a battle of poli-tical parties. As argued at the outset, the adoption of a new frame is relatively straightforward if it happens to be consistent with established policy approaches and the concerns of strong, organized interests. If not, then only the third battle – electoral politics – can generate the political energy required to overturn conventional wisdom in policy circles and challenge the preferences of strongly organized interests. That is precisely the situation in Canada today. An inequality frame, especially one that emphasizes income redistribution, runs counter to both embedded policy thinking and the preferences of the strongest organized interests in the country. Only electoral politics can generate the political firepower to overcome such resistance, and the prospects there are uncertain at best.

The battle of ideas

Einstein once complained that “everything has changed except our ideas.” In Canada, a policy frame calling for enhanced redistribution confronts conventional policy wisdom on both the expenditure and revenue sides. On the expenditure side, it runs against the grain of the doctrine of social investment; on the revenue side, it challenges established tax doctrine.

During the 1990s, faith in explicit redistribution through the tax-and-transfer system gave way throughout the OECD to enthusiasm for a social investment model (Banting 2006). The proposed cures included a stick and a carrot. Policy-makers held that, with one hand, governments should cut back on “passive” programs such as unemployment insurance and social assistance to make labour markets more “flexible.” With the other hand, governments should increase social investment in education and training and in “active” labour market programs to facilitate job search and eventual employment (Jenson 2013). In effect, social policy should be about investing in human capital, rather than redistributing income. Policy attention, according to this approach, should focus in particular on children, to ensure they have a rich learning environment, especially in the early years. In addition, young people should be educated to higher levels than in the past, and learning should become a lifelong process. Citizens should upgrade their skills continually, and training programs should reequip older workers displaced by the forces of “creative destruction” inherent in economic growth.

The pervasiveness of this approach is striking. At the international level, its diffusion was led by the OECD, especially through its Jobs Study and a stream of successor documents (OECD 1994, 1995, 1996, 1999). The same themes came to pervade Canadian discourse, shaping government planning documents and policy initiatives (Green and Townsend 2013). But Canadian follow-up has been decidedly one-sided. The country emerged as a poster child for retrenchment of “passive” income transfers: in the mid- to late 1990s, major programs transferring income to working-age adults were retrenched, with the biggest cuts falling on employment insurance benefits and social assistance. In contrast, new public investment in human capital formation and “active” labour market programs has been tepid. An analysis of OECD data suggests that Canadian public spending on education and job training as a whole has declined significantly since 1980 (Nikolai 2012). Moreover, with the exception of the expansion of child care programs in Quebec and a more modest initiative that introduced full-day kindergarten in Ontario, investment in early childhood education has drifted. Canada falls well below the pattern in many other democratic countries, provoking disappointing rankings in international scorecards (OECD 2004; UNICEF 2008).8

It is not difficult to understand why the stick succeeded and the carrot failed. Cutting passive social expenditures saves money; new social investments in education, training and active labour market policy cost money. The costs are especially high for countries like Canada that are starting out close to square one on these fronts. According to the OECD (2012), Canada ranks 36th out of 36 OECD countries on the enrolment of three-year-olds, and 35th out of 38 on that of four-year-olds, in early childhood education. New social investments require new revenue, which probably means higher taxes. Despite this drift in terms of implementation, however, the doctrine of social investment remains entrenched, and represents a potent barrier to calls for a return to direct income redistribution as a primary goal of social policy.

The second entrenched paradigm that stands in the way of redistribution is the revolution in tax doctrine. The Second World War served as the stimulus for the growth of mass taxation and rising state revenues: in most developed countries, revenues as a share of gross domestic product (GDP) doubled between 1930 and 1945 (Steinmo 2003, 213). At war’s end, there was an expectation that taxes would be rolled back to prewar levels, but that did not happen. As the logic of Keynesian economic management took hold, policy elites saw taxation policy as a tool for enhancing economic efficiency and for providing revenue for health care, education and income redistribution. Moreover, it was widely assumed that equity concerns should drive tax design, which should be anchored in a comprehensive and progressive income tax system. This belief was captured in Canada by the Royal Commission on Taxation (1966), with its mantra that “a dollar is a dollar no matter what its source.”

All of that changed with the dramatic slowing of economic growth in the 1970s and the failure of Keynesianism. Beginning in the United States and the United Kingdom, newly ascendant doctrines insisted that the tax system should be concerned more with efficiency than with equity; that capital gains should be taxed at lower rates, if at all; that progressive taxes have disincentive effects; and that the tax mix should shift from income taxes to consumption taxes. In addition, fiscal elites became disillusioned with the idea of using tax incentives to achieve social and economic goals. Loopholes, credits and deductions, in an increasingly complex tax system, led to growing tax expenditures. As Steinmo (2003, 216) shows, tax policy experts on both the left and the right concluded that tax expenditures were simply “giveaways to the rich and powerful.”9

The revolution in tax doctrine also brought a major shift in considerations of who should pay. Income taxes were first introduced as a method to finance the First World War and were based on the principle of “ability to pay,” which led to a tax on corporate profits and the incomes of the highest-income earners. Mass taxation arrived with the Second World War, and income taxes moved down the income scale but retained their prewar character of “progressive” taxation based on ability to pay. Slemrod (1995) documents just how radically opinion had changed by the 1990s. He surveyed a sample of 503 members of the U.S. National Tax Association in Canada and the US in 1994 in order to compare their responses with an identical survey of senior finance professionals conducted in 1934. In 1934, 66 percent agreed that there should be higher taxes on unearned (i.e., capital) income, compared with only 6 percent in 1994; 12 percent supported retail sales taxes at the state level in 1934, compared with 91 percent 50 years later.

Although the revolution in tax doctrine began elsewhere, it quickly permeated Canadian thinking. Professional advice on taxation policy moved from equity to efficiency considerations, and penetrated deeply into Canadian tax policy, diminishing its redistributive effects (Boadway and Cuff 2013). As Don Drummond (2011), former assistant deputy minister of finance, recalls, reducing marginal tax rates and corporate tax rates was a central part of the finance department’s strategy to raise productivity in the 1990s – a strategy that failed, however, to produce the promised productivity dividends. Nevertheless, tax cutting continued into the 2000s. Between the late 1990s and 2012, total government revenues from all sources fell from roughly 45 percent to 38 percent of GDP, a massive drop in the resources available to government (Richards 2014, 136).

Clearly, an emphasis on inequality and income redistribution runs against the grain of conventional wisdom in Canadian policy circles. The search for poli-tical ammunition needs to be broadened.

The battle of organized interests

In many OECD countries, the politics of organized interests and the structure of political institutions have provided some help to advocates of low-income groups, limiting the turn away from redistribution on both the program and tax sides. Their Canadian counterparts have not benefited in the same way.

To start, Canada has always lacked the corporatist institutions that have provided blocking mechanisms elsewhere. “Corporatism,” and related metaphors such as “social pacts” and “social partners,” are generally unfamiliar to North Americans. The term refers to systems of economic governance common in northern Europe, where the state and extraparliamentary bodies representing peak organizations of business and labour (the “social partners”) traditionally made decisions jointly on labour market and social policy regulations. Cross-national studies suggest that resistance to retrenchment has been strongest in countries with corporatist institutions (Hicks and Kenworthy 1998). Although such institutions have been weakening in many European countries in recent years (Beramendi et al. 2015), they still make it difficult simply to ignore organized labour.

Canada, in contrast, lacks decision-making institutions that ensure access for extraparliamentary economic interests. The influence of civil society advocates for the economic interests of lower-income Canadians has also weakened in recent decades. As a proportion of the labour force, union membership declined from 38 percent to 30 percent between 1981 and 2012, mainly due to large declines in the private sector. Antipoverty groups, women’s organizations, advisory bodies and think tanks, the traditional champions of the interests of the disadvantaged, have lost public funding and literally disappeared from the public forum (Phillips 2013). Charitable civil society organizations that advocate egalitarian policies have been harassed by tax officials for their political activities. This decline has not been offset by greater political activity on the part of “bottom-third” Canadians, who remain less likely to turn out to vote or to participate in other ways (Gidengil et al. 2004). Political parties have less incentive to worry about them than about the highly attentive and vociferous affluent voter.

Changes in the distribution of power within Canada’s political institutions have also raised the barriers to concerted action against inequality. Within governments, power has shifted from social policy departments to departments of finance and to greater political control by prime ministers and premiers. In Ottawa, the centralization of political power in the Prime Minister’s Office and of bureaucratic power in the Department of Finance has eroded the advocacy role once played by ministers in line social departments for their programs and clients. Between governments, power has shifted from the federal to the provincial level. Quebec has made use of its additional policy space to chart a different policy trajectory, one that continues to offset growth in inequality (NoĂ«l 2013). Elsewhere, however, redistribution has weakened more at the provincial level than at the federal level in recent decades (Fortin et al. 2012). In addition, the rising economic importance of resource-rich western provinces has generated new interprovincial cleavages. Where once the division between Quebec and the Rest of Canada was the defining cleavage in the federation, the division between the West and the rest has become more intense, and the exclusion of resource revenues from federal equalization payments has widened the gap in the capacity of provinces to respond to new social stresses (Boadway 2013; Bricker and Ibbitson 2013).

Taken together, these two trends are decisive. Institutional barriers to change mean that considerable political momentum will be needed, but the organizations that propelled redistributive strategies in the past are weaker today than at any point since the Second World War. From where can political momentum come? Only electoral politics can generate the traction needed.

The battle of political parties

Canada has always relied heavily on political parties to develop cross-country coalitions. Parties are almost unique in attempting to build national constituencies, seeking to bridge the regional and linguistic divides that define the country. Remarkably few civil society institutions have vibrant organizations that speak authoritatively for their sector across the country as a whole (Cameron and Simeon 2009). As a result, building a pan-Canadian consensus on social policy through the channels of civil society is a difficult task, leaving political parties less constrained.10

The only other political contender for the role of coalition builder has been executive federalism: the process of intergovernmental negotiations among federal, provincial and territorial governments. Historically, such negotiations have been critical to the development of public policy, especially social policy, in Canada (Simeon 2006). On their own, however, intergovernmental negotiations seldom change policy directions. Such discussions come into effect only when political momentum has developed behind policy proposals that transcend jurisdictional boundaries. Absent such political drive, executive federalism does not kick into gear, as witnessed by its decline under the current government.

Given the weakness in Canada of constraints found in other countries, redistribution policy is especially sensitive to shifts in party politics, and -realigning elections have powerful implications. Canadian electoral politics has never been class based. Indeed, in a study of the “Anglo-American” democracies published a half-century ago, US scholar Robert Alford described Canada as a case of “pure non-class voting” (1963, x-xi). Although subsequent studies have marginally qualified the observation, the central conclusion remains robust: the Canadian electorate is much less likely than those in many other democracies to vote along class lines, whether measured by income, education or occupation. To a level unusual among Western democracies, Canada’s electoral cleavages are rooted in religion, language, ethnicity and region.11

Nevertheless, political parties and electoral politics matter for redistribution. Richard Johnston (2013) has demonstrated the ways in which the dramatic fragmentation of the old party system in the 1993 election facilitated deep cuts to federal transfer programs in that decade. The following decade saw a dramatic polarization of the party system: the historic centre-dominated party system of the postwar era, with its ideologically flexible brokerage parties, was replaced by one more polarized on a left-right basis. This ideological realignment among the parties has triggered an ideological “sorting” at the level of voters. Soroka and Kevins (2014) demonstrate this electoral sorting in the case of attitudes to redistribution. Strikingly, in the 1988 election, voters for the three main parties differed little in their attitudes toward income redistribution; Progressive Conservative voters were, if anything, a little to the left of Liberal voters. By the 2011 election, in contrast, Conservative voters were clearly to the right of the other parties on redistributive issues, New -Democratic- Party (NDP) voters were on the left and Liberal voters were in the middle. Johnston (2015) demonstrates the resulting polarization, this time in terms of voters’ self-declared ideological leanings; by the mid-2000s, parties’ supporters were highly differentiated ideologically, with NDP supporters on the left, Conservatives on the right and Liberals holding up the middle (see figure 4). Canada might not have class politics, but it now has a more ideologically polarized party politics. Voters have a clearer sense of where parties stand on redistributive issues, and can choose accordingly.

It is unclear whether Canada’s polarized party system will persist. Whatever the future configuration of the party system, however, it is clear that political parties of all stripes will require strong incentives to mount a major campaign against inequality in its contemporary form. Studies of other countries (Iversen and Soskice 2006) suggest that the politics of redistribution increasingly depends on whether middle-class voters align with the top or with the bottom of the income distribution. When middle-class voters identify with upper-income groups, they are more likely to join the clamour for tax cuts. Is there a prospect that, as upper-income groups pull further away from the middle, segments of the middle or lower-middle class might support greater redistribution? In recent years, a number of social policy reforms in Europe have been driven by such coalitions. Left parties, faced with declines in their traditional working-class constituencies, have forged new coalitions by courting segments of the middle class, including working women, precarious workers and salaried professionals (Thelen 2014; Häusermann 2010).

Banting-Myles fig4

Family policy has shown a capacity to appeal to such cross-class coalitions (Morgan 2006, 2012). In addition to international examples, the Quebec experience provides a concrete counterpoint to the more general Canadian experience. There, a series of family- and child-centred reforms between 1996 and 2006, including daycare, parental leave and enhanced child benefits, put the brakes on the inequality surge and lowered poverty rates while raising taxes on higher-income households and households without children (Noël 2013). The focus on families and children appealed not only to progressives, but also to more traditional, family-oriented Quebec values and to families at both the middle and bottom of the income distribution.

Presumably, similar opportunities exist in Canada more generally. Stagnant average incomes, declining relative earnings for the young and weakening occupational benefits such as pensions are fuel for a debate about the social needs of the middle and lower-middle classes. A sense of economic security tradi-tionally has been seen as a core element of middle-class life, but public opinion surveys increasingly reveal a sense of economic insecurity among middle-class respondents. Strikingly, the proportion of Canadians self-identifying as middle class declined from about 68 percent in 2002 to 47 percent in 2014 (Graves 2014). Middle-income respondents express anxiety about their economic prospects, their family finances, their debt levels, their retirement income and the prospects for their children. They also harbour a vague sense that the growing concentration of income and wealth is unfair (Graves 2014; Herle 2014). These anxieties could generate greater scope for cross-class support for policies aimed at protecting both middle- and low-income Canadians.12

Nothing is guaranteed here. The emotional appeal of lower taxes and less spending might well trump less viscerally engaging arguments for progressive taxation or fixing the public plumbing. The institutionalization of antitax doctrine is well advanced in Canada, and taps into other currents in public opinion: a general sense of risk aversion and a decline in trust in government that has been ongoing for decades (Nevitte 2002). As a result, antitax sentiment is difficult to change. Higher consumption taxes are unpopular over most of the income distribution. Higher marginal tax rates for the top third will meet resistance from legions of economic pundits and from the very attentive voters in those income brackets. Taxing wealth by restoring inheritance taxes would be resisted by Piketty’s petits rentiers (families of modest wealth) as well by the top 10 percent, and would require unprecedented federal-provincial cooperation, since that power was left to the provinces in 1971 and they quickly abandoned the tax (Banting 1991).

Tax phobia has infected all Canadian political parties to varying degrees. As Alex Himelfarb, former clerk of the Privy Council, puts it, in recent decades “tax” has become a four-letter word among policy elites and political parties of all stripes (Himelfarb and Himelfarb 2013). The barriers here are not absolute. Under intense budgetary pressures, several provinces have gingerly taken small steps toward more progressive taxes. The Ontario government introduced modest tax increases on high-income earners in 2012 and 2014. The 2012 increase affected the top 0.2 percent of tax filers, while the 2014 increase affected the top 2 percent of income earners – those with taxable income over $150,000 (Ontario 2014, chap. 5).13 In the face of steep declines in resource revenues, the governments of Newfoundland and Labrador and Alberta introduced new tax brackets for higher-income earners in their 2015 budgets. In Alberta’s case this meant phasing out its symbolic flat tax (Newfoundland and Labrador 2015; Alberta 2015). Despite such initiatives, however, tax cuts remain an effective electoral strategy since they produce only winners: everyone has more money in their pocket. Tax cuts are never introduced alongside a list of the program cuts that surely must follow from declining revenue, so the “losers” are hidden from view at election time (Mackenzie 2013).

As we write, the 2015 federal election campaign is beginning and the major national political parties are jostling with one another to identify the “winning” frame. Strikingly, none of the parties have thus far adopted a “war on poverty” frame. That does not mean that poverty has entirely disappeared from the agenda; all reform proposals quickly get evaluated by the experts from the perspective of who wins over the entire income distribution, including those at the bottom. Nevertheless, the redistributive agenda has shifted sharply to focus on a vaguely defined “middle class,” not the “poor.”14 The new question then becomes one of who gets to define and embrace the “middle class,” a challenging project for all political parties.

In November 2014, the NDP took a first step by proposing a national child care program modelled on the Quebec system and delivered through a federal-provincial program. In May 2015, the Liberal Party proposed a reduction in taxes for middle-income taxpayers, a tax increase for the top (those with over $200,000 of taxable income) and an expansion of child benefits that would help lower-income families most. The Conservative government’s position was rolled out over two years. In 2014, it announced a complex restructuring of family-related tax measures, the centrepiece of which was the introduction of income splitting for two-parent families (which would benefit less than 15 percent of families, most with six-figure incomes). The package also included increases in the Universal Child Care Benefit and the Child Care Expense Deduction, and the elimination of the Child Tax Credit. Analysts agreed that the package as a whole delivers most benefits to better-off families, who are more likely to vote, less to middle-income families and least to low-income families.15 In its 2015 budget, the government added a major increase in the maximum annual contribution to Tax-Free Savings Accounts, a proposal that virtually all analysts agree also skews benefits to higher-income, higher-wealth and older families (Finance Canada 2015).

The still emergent party platforms represent an array of responses, with different redistributive implications. All are focused on helping “families,” a theme with strong electoral appeal for many, but not all, as the share of traditional “families” declines among the electorate. And electoral appeals to the middle class require both parties and electors to make strategic and complex calculations about who will be counted among the middle class. Moreover, as we have stressed, much depends on whether middle-income voters see their interests as aligned with upper-income groups or with lower-income groups when responding to choices.

Conclusion

We end as we began: redistributive politics in Canada has been stuck for several decades. Debates about the new inequality have been unfocused, reflecting disagreement about what is happening and whether it matters. Although modest, a reframing is now beginning to take shape as a result of electoral politics and party competition.

Canada is struggling to define or frame contemporary social stresses. The antipoverty frame built into Canada’s public discourse and institutions has been fading. Yet new frames that highlight the new inequality – the 99/1 and middle–class frames – are still jostling to hold public attention and alter conventional wisdom among policy elites. The result is a period of flux in Canadian debates.

At a deeper level, contemporary efforts to frame social issues represent a political struggle to set the direction of Canadian social policy in the years to come. In this struggle, a new inequality frame confronts serious constraints in the form of conventional wisdom among policy elites, the unequal representation of economic interests and much-changed party and political institutions. The top one-third of income earners have learned how to take advantage of the new economy and the new politics, while the bottom two-thirds are still struggling. What are the chances that governments will act to close the growing income gap? Only electoral politics can generate the political momentum to overturn established policy norms and powerful economic interests, but the prospects for building the momentum required to address the new inequality are uncertain. All political parties are responding to the anxieties of the middle class and proclaim themselves ready to help families. But not all policies advanced to help families reflect an egalitarian impulse. Some policies advanced in the name of the middle class would actually assist upper-income earners even more, and are likely to exacerbate inequality.

The centrist brokerage politics responsible for social policy initiatives in the past has been swept away – temporarily, at least – by the polarization of the party system and the electorate, making the stakes in elections much higher. The struggle to frame the stresses we face will be central to the electoral politics of 2015 and beyond.

We wish to thank David Green, France -St-Hilaire, Paul Pierson, Craig Riddell, Scott Matthews and Francesca Worrall for important comments on earlier versions of this paper. We thank especially Richard Johnston and Michael Veall for making their data available.

  1. We use the term redistribution in its narrow sense to refer to second-round redistribution of income through taxes and transfers after first-round distribution in the market. But markets themselves are created by states, beginning with the institution of private property and extending through the regulation of labour, product and financial markets and the feedback, second-order effects of transfers and taxes on market behaviour. In this broader sense, all public policy is “redistributive.”
  2. Longitudinal Administrative Databank, 4107; results supplied by Brian Murphy, Statistics Canada.
  3. A substantial literature in political psychology explores the effects of the framing of issues on public attitudes about them. For a useful review of the general literature, see Chong and Druckman (2007); for applications in the field of social policy, see Gilens (1996) and Mendelberg (2001). There is less research on the politics of framing among policy elites, which is the focus of this chapter (but see Surel 2000). However, our approach is informed by the institutionalist literature on the role of ideas in policy change (BĂ©land 2005; Blyth 2002; Hall 1993).
  4. This outcome was anticipated in much of the comparative literature contrasting welfare states targeted at the poor versus more encompassing welfare states aimed at a majority of the electorate (Korpi and Palme 1998).
  5. Interestingly, Piketty’s thesis was foreshadowed in a Finance Canada consultation paper (1996) that explained why it was necessary to shift the financing of the Canada Pension Plan away from payroll taxes (“returns to labour”) toward greater capitalization (“returns to capital”).
  6. One sign of the sensitivity of the issues has been the controversy over the different conclusions drawn by reports prepared by Employment and Social Development Canada and Finance Canada (Beeby 2014a, 2014b).
  7. In 1959, President Dwight Eisenhower reportedly invited Premier Nikita Khrushchev on a helicopter ride over the Washington suburbs to demonstrate what democratic capitalism could do for “workers.” Khrushchev declined.
  8. These decisions and nondecisions help explain why public social expenditures (including income transfers and public health care spending) now represent a smaller proportion of gross domestic product in Canada than in the United States (see the OECD’s Social Expenditure database, https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?datasetcode=SOCX_AGG; accessed May 1, 2015).
  9. In a recent essay, Scott Clark, former deputy minister of finance, concludes that little has changed in this respect (Clark 2013).
  10. This pattern finds parallels in other countries. A recent interpretation argues that traditionally powerful economic interests, especially organized labour, have weakened in advanced capitalist economies generally, and that there has been an “electoral turn” in politics, with parties and elections emerging as the primary mechanism of collective mobilization in contemporary democracies (Beramendi et al. 2015).
  11. For a useful survey of studies exploring these issues, see the various contributions to Kanji, Bilodeau and Scott (2012).
  12. Recent empirical research suggests that public support for the welfare state is greater when risk is widely spread among the population (Rehm, Hacker and Schlesinger 2012).
  13. The tax increases netted $635 million in fiscal year 2014-15, a modest contribution to reducing the deficit of an estimated $12 billion (Ontario 2014, chap. 5).
  14. Interestingly, the word poverty does not appear in the Liberal Party’s exposition of its proposed Canada Child Benefit. The document refers several times to “the middle class and those working hard to join it” (Liberal Party of Canada 2015).
  15. These analysts include Scott Clark, former deputy minister of finance (Clark and
    deVries 2014). See also Battle and -Torjman (2014) and Kesselman (2014). For an analysis of the Conservative Party’s original proposal for income splitting, see Laurin and Kesselman (2011).

Alberta. 2015. Budget 2015: Fiscal Plan. Edmonton: Ministry of Finance. Accessed May 8, 2015. https://finance.alberta.ca/publications/budget/budget2015/fiscal-plan-complete.pdf

Alford, R. 1963. Party and Society: The Anglo-American Democracies. Chicago: Rand McNally.

Avdagic, S., M. Rhodes, and J. Visser. 2011. Social Pacts in Europe: Emergence, Evolution and Institutionalization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Banting, K. 1991. “The Politics of Wealth Taxes.” Canadian Public Policy 17 (3): 351-67.

_____. 2006. “Disembedding Liberalism: The New Social Policy Paradigm in Canada.” In Dimensions of Inequality in Canada, edited by D. Green and J. Kesselman. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Banting, K., and J. Myles, eds. 2013. Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Battle, K., and S. Torjman. 2014. “The Elephant Not in the Room.” Caledon Commentary, October. Ottawa: Caledon Institute of Social Policy.

Beach, C. 2014. “What Has Happened to Middle-Class Earnings? Distributional Shifts in Earnings in Canada, 1970-2005.” CLSRN Working Paper 131. Vancouver: Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network.

Beeby, D. 2014a. “Middle-Class Dreams a Myth in Troubled Economy: Internal Government Report.” Globe and Mail, February 23.

_____. 2014b. “Finance Canada Now Sees Middle-Class Families in Rosy Hue.” CBC News, September 1. Accessed April 29, 2015. https://www.cbc.ca/news/politics/finance-canada-now-sees-middle-class-families-in-rosy-hue-1.2752344

Béland, D. 2005. “Ideas and Social Policy: An Institutionalist Perspective.” Social Policy and Administration 39 (1): 1-18.

Beramendi, P., S. Häusermann, H. Kitschelt, and H. Kriesi. eds. 2015. The Politics of Advanced Capitalism. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Bluestone, B., and B. Harrison. 1982. The Deindustrialization of America. New York: Basic Books.

Blyth, M. 2002. Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Boadway, R. 2013. “Taxes and Transfers in Canada: The Federal Dimension.” In Tax Is Not a Four-Letter Word: A Different Take on Taxes in Canada, edited by A. Himelfarb and J. Himelfarb. Waterloo, ON: Wilfrid Laurier University Press.

Boadway, R., and K. Cuff. 2013. “The Recent Evolution of Tax-Transfer Policies.” In Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics, edited by K. Banting and J. Myles. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Bricker, D., and J. Ibbitson. 2013. The Big Shift: The Seismic Change in Canadian Politics, Business and Culture, and What It Means for Our Future. Toronto: HarperCollins.

Cameron, D., and R. Simeon, eds. 2009. Language Matters: How Canadian Voluntary Associations Manage French and English. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Chong, D., and J. Druckman. 2007. “Framing Theory.” Annual Review of Political Science 10: 103-26.

Clark, S. 2013. “We Need to Simplify and Refocus the Tax System.” In Tax Is Not a Four-Letter Word: A Different Take on Taxes in Canada, edited by A. Himelfarb and J. Himelfarb. Waterloo, ON: Wilfrid Laurier University Press.

Clark, S., and P. deVries. 2014. “These Are the Wrong Tax Cuts for an Economy in Peril.” iPolitics, November 4. Accessed April 29, 2015. https://www.ipolitics.ca/2014/11/04/these-are-the-wrong-tax-cuts-for-an-economy-in-peril/

Corak, M. 2014. “Two Stories about Inequality and the Middle Class.” Paper presented at the Queen’s University International Institute on Social Policy, August 19, Kingston, ON. Accessed April 29, 2015. https://www.queensu.ca/sps/events/conferencesandworkshops/qiisp/2014/presentations/MilesCorakQIISP14.pdf

Drummond, D. 2011. “Confessions of a Serial Productivity Researcher.” International Productivity Monitor 22: 3-10.

Feldstein, M. 1998. “Income Inequality and Poverty.” NBER Working Paper 6770. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Finance Canada. 1996. An Information Paper for Consultations on the Canada Pension Plan: Released by the Federal, Provincial and Territorial Governments of Canada. Ottawa: Finance Canada.

_____. 2015. Strong Leadership: A Balanced-Budget, Low-Tax Plan for Jobs, Growth and Security. Accessed May 8, 2015. Ottawa: Department of Finance. https://www.budget.gc.ca/2015/docs/plan/budget2015-eng.pdf

Fortin, N., D. Green, T. Lemieux, K. Milligan, and C. Riddell. 2012. “Canadian Inequality: Recent Developments and Policy Options.” Canadian Public Policy 38 (2): 121-45.

Fortin, N.M., and T. Lemieux. Forthcoming. “Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective.” Canadian Journal of Economics.

Gidengil, E., A. Blais, N. Nevitte, and R. Nadeau, 2004. Citizens. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Gilens, M. 1996. “Race and Poverty in America: Public Misperceptions and the American News Media.” Public Opinion Quarterly 60 (4): 515-41.

Good, D. 2013. “The New Bureaucratic Politics of Redistribution.” In Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics, edited by K. Banting and J. Myles. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Graves, F. 2014. “From the End of History to the End of Progress: The Shifting Meaning of Middle Class.” Paper presented at the Queen’s University International Institute on Social Policy, August 19, Kingston, ON. Accessed April 29, 2015. https://www.queensu.ca/sps/events/conferencesandworkshops/qiisp/2014/presentations/FrankGravesQIISP14.pdf

Green, D., and J. Townsend. 2013. “Drivers of Increasing Market Income Inequality: Structural Change and Policy.” In Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics, edited by K. Banting and J. Myles. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Hacker, J., and P. Pierson. 2010. Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich Richer – and Turned Its Back on the Middle Class. New York: Simon & Schuster.

Hall, P. 1993. “Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain.” Comparative Politics 25 (3): 275-96.

Häusermann, S. 2010. The Politics of Welfare State Reform in Continental Europe. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Herle, D. 2014. “What Does the Middle Class Want?” The Gandalf Group. Paper presented at the Queen’s University International Institute on Social Policy, August 20, Kingston, ON. Accessed April 29, 2015. https://www.queensu.ca/sps/events/conferencesandworkshops/qiisp/2014/presentations/DavidHerleQIISP14.pdf

Hicks, A., and L. Kenworthy. 1998. “Cooperation and Political Economic Performance in Affluent Democratic Capitalism.” American Journal of Sociology 103 (6): 1631-72.

Himelfarb, A., and J. Himelfarb, eds. 2013. Tax Is Not a Four-Letter Word. Waterloo, ON: Wilfrid Laurier University Press.

Iversen, T., and D. Soskice. 2006. “Electoral Institutions and the Politics of Coalitions: Why Some Democracies Redistribute More Than Others.” American Political Science Review 100 (2): 165-81.

Jenson, J. 2013. “Historical Transformations of Canada’s Social Architecture: Institutions, Instruments and Ideas.” In Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics, edited by K. Banting and J. Myles. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Johnston, R. 2013. “The Party System, Elections, and Social Policy.” In Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics, edited by K. Banting and J. Myles. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

_____. 2015. “Canada Is Polarizing – and It’s because of the Parties,” in Political Polarization in American Politics, edited by D. J. Hopkins and J. Sides. New York: Bloomsbury.

Kanji, M., A. Bilodeau, and T. Scotto, eds. 2012. The Canadian Election Studies: Assessing Four Decades of Influence. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Keister, L. 2014. “The One Percent.” Annual Review of Sociology 40: 147-67.

Kesselman, J. 2014. Family Tax Cuts: How Inclusive a Family? Ottawa: Caledon Institute of Social Policy.

Korpi, W., and J. Palme. 1998. “The Paradox of Redistribution and Strategies of Inequality: Welfare State Institutions, Inequality, and Poverty in the Western Countries.” American Sociological Review 63: 661-87.

Kuznets, S. 1955. “Economic Growth and Income Inequality.” American Economic Review 45 (1): 1-28.

Laurin, A., and J.R. Kesselman. 2011. Income Splitting for Two-Parent Families: Who Gains, Who Doesn’t, and at What Cost? Commentary 335. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute.

Leonhardt, D., and K. Quealy. 2014. “The American Middle Class Is No Longer the World’s Richest.” New York Times, April 22. Accessed April 29, 2015. https://www.nytimes.com/2014/04/23/upshot/the-american-middle-class-is-no-longer-the-worlds-richest.html?abt=0002&abg=1

Liberal Party of Canada. 2015. Justin Trudeau’s Plan for Fairness for the Middle Class. Accessed May 12, 2015. https://www.liberal.ca/files/2015/05/Fairness-for-the-Middle-Class.pdf

Mackenzie, H. 2013. “Taxes and Public Services.” In Tax Is Not a Four-Letter Word: A Different Take on Taxes in Canada, edited by A. Himelfarb and J. Himelfarb. Waterloo, ON: Wilfrid Laurier University Press.

March, J., and H. Simon. 1958. Organizations. New York: John Wiley.

Mendelberg, T. 2001. The Race Card: Campaign Strategy, Implicit Messages, and the Norm of Equality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Morgan, K. 2006. Working Mothers and the Welfare State: Religion and the Politics of Work-Family Practices in Western Europe and the United States. Redwood City, CA: Stanford University Press.

_____. 2012. “Promoting Social Investment through Work-Family Policies: Which Nations Do It and Why?” in Towards a Social Investment Welfare State: Ideas, Policies and Challenges, edited by N. Morel, B. Palier, and J. Palme. Bristol, UK: Policy Press.

Myles, J., and P. Pierson. 1997. “Friedman’s Revenge: The Reform of Liberal’ Welfare States in Canada and the United States.” Politics and Society 25: 443-72.

Nevitte, N., ed. 2002. Value Change and Governance in Canada. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Newfoundland and Labrador. 2015. Budget 2015. St. John’s: Ministry of Finance. Accessed May 8, 2015. https://www.budget.gov.nl.ca/budget2015/highlights/highlights_2015.pdf

Nikolai, R. 2012. “Mapping the Development of Social Investment Policies.” In Towards a Social Investment State? Ideas, Policies and Challenges, edited by N. Morel, B. Palier, and J. Palme. Bristol, UK: Policy Press.

NoĂ«l, A. 2013. “Quebec’s New Politics of Redistribution.” In Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics, edited by K. Banting and J. Myles. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

OECD (see Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development)

Ontario. 2014. Ontario Budget 2014: Building Opportunity, Securing Our Future. Accessed April 29, 2015. https://www.fin.gov.on.ca/en/budget/ontariobudgets/2014/papers_all.html

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 1994. The OECD Jobs Study: Facts, Analysis, Strategies. Paris: OECD Publishing.

_____. 1995. The OECD Jobs Study: Implementing the Strategy. Paris: OECD Publishing.

_____. 1996. The OECD Jobs Strategy: Pushing Ahead with the Strategy. Paris: OECD Publishing.

_____. 1999. Implementing the OECD Jobs Strategy: Assessing Performance and Policy. Paris: OECD Publishing.

_____. 2004. Directorate for Education. Early Childhood Education and Care Policy: Canada Country Note. Paris: OECD Publishing.

_____. 2011. Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising. Paris: OECD Publishing.

_____. 2012. Education at a Glance. Paris: OECD Publishing.

_____. 2014. Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs. Focus on Top Incomes and Taxation in OECD Countries: Was the Crisis a Game Changer? Paris: OECD Publishing.

Phillips, S. 2013. “Restructuring Civil Society.” In Inequality and the Fading of Redistributive Politics, edited by K. Banting and J. Myles. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

Piketty, T. 2014. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Rehm, P., J. Hacker, and M. Schlesinger. 2012. “Insecure Alliances: Risk, Inequality, and Support for the Welfare State.” American Political Science Review 106 (2): 386-406.

Richards, J. 2014. “A Determined Effort to Understand Inequality.” Inroads 35 (Summer/Fall): 133-42.

Royal Commission on Taxation. 1966. Report of the Royal Commission on Taxation. Ottawa: Queen’s Printer.

Simeon, R. 2006. Federal-Provincial Diplomacy: The Making of Recent Policy in Canada. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Slemrod, J. 1995. “Professional Opinions about Tax Policy: 1994 and 1934.” National Tax Journal 48 (1): 121-47.

Soroka, S., and A. Kevins. 2014. “Redistributive Preferences and Partisan Polarization: Canada in Comparative Perspective.” Paper prepared for Canadianizing the United States? Public Opinion across the 49th Parallel, May 9, Institute for Governmental Studies, University of California Berkeley.

Starr, P. 2014. “A Different Road to a Fair Society.” New York Review of Books, May 22, 33-36.

Steinmo, S. 2003. “The Evolution of Policy Ideas: Tax Policy in the 20th Century.” British Journal of Politics and International Relations 5 (2): 206-36.

Stiglitz, J. 2012. The Price of Inequality: How Today’s Divided Society Endangers Our Future. New York: W.W. Norton.

Surel, Y. 2000. “The Role of Cognitive and Normative Frames in Policy-Making.” Journal of European Public Policy 7 (4): 495-512.

Thelen, K. 2014. Varieties of Liberalization and the New Politics of Social Solidarity. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

UNICEF. 2008. The Child Care Transition: A League Table of Early Childhood Education and Care in Economically Advanced Countries. Innocenti Report Card 8. Florence, Italy: UNICEF Innocenti Research Centre.

Veall, M. 2012. “Top Income Shares in Canada: Recent Trends and Policy Implications.” Canadian Journal of Economics 45: 1247-72.

Les prochaines Ă©lections fĂ©dĂ©rales dĂ©termineront l’orientation des politiques en matière d’inĂ©galitĂ© des revenus

MontrĂ©al – La question de la redistribution des revenus au Canada n’a pas Ă©voluĂ© depuis plusieurs dĂ©cennies, en raison de points de vue divergents sur l’importance des inĂ©galitĂ©s de revenu et le problème de politique publique qu’elles reprĂ©sentent. Mais Ă  l’approche d’Ă©lections fĂ©dĂ©rales qui s’annoncent très serrĂ©es, des efforts en vue de reformuler cet enjeu se dessinent, selon une nouvelle Ă©tude de l’IRPP.

En 30 ans, l’inĂ©galitĂ© des revenus du marchĂ© a sensiblement augmentĂ© au Canada, Ă  tel point que le 1 p. 100 le plus riche de la population s’est accaparĂ© 37 p. 100 de la croissance du revenu national. Et face Ă  l’Ă©chĂ©ance Ă©lectorale, la manière de dĂ©finir ou d’« encadrer » cette inĂ©galitĂ© grandissante fait l’objet d’un vif dĂ©bat, notent les auteurs Keith Banting et John Myles.

Dans ce chapitre d’un ouvrage Ă  paraĂ®tre, intitulĂ© Income Inequality: The Canadian Story, les deux chercheurs examinent donc les enjeux politiques entourant cette question.

« Historiquement inscrit dans les institutions canadiennes, le cadre antipauvretĂ© perd rapidement du terrain, estiment-ils. Mais de nouveaux cadres politiques comme celui du 1 p. 100 le plus riche et celui toujours contestĂ© de la classe moyenne rivalisent entre eux pour retenir l’attention du public et bousculer les idĂ©es reçues de nos Ă©lites politiques. »

Or, chacun de ces trois cadres nĂ©cessite une redistribution considĂ©rable des revenus, mais sous diffĂ©rentes formes. La mise en Ĺ“uvre d’une meilleure redistribution se heurtera nĂ©anmoins Ă  de fortes contraintes, notamment aux normes d’intervention Ă©tablies, Ă  la reprĂ©sentation inĂ©gale des intĂ©rĂŞts Ă©conomiques et Ă  un contexte institutionnel et politique sensiblement changĂ©.

« Le tiers le plus riche des Canadiens a su tirer profit de la nouvelle Ă©conomie et de ce nouvel environnement politique, constatent les auteurs, mais les deux tiers restants n’ont pas amĂ©liorĂ© leur sort. Et c’est Ă  nos dirigeants politiques qu’il revient de combler cet Ă©cart grandissant des revenus en s’attaquant aux pratiques actuelles d’investissement social, Ă  la fiscalitĂ© et aux transferts. »

Si tous les partis disent vouloir aider les familles, les mesures qu’ils prĂ©conisent ne traduisent pas toujours cet Ă©lan Ă©galitaire, ajoutent Banting et Myles. Ils croient donc qu’en dernier ressort, seuls les Ă©lecteurs de la classe moyenne pourront favoriser cette dynamique d’Ă©galitĂ©, selon qu’ils jugent leurs intĂ©rĂŞts compatibles avec ceux des groupes Ă  revenu faible ou alors ceux Ă  revenu Ă©levĂ©.

On peut tĂ©lĂ©charger ce chapitre sur le site de l’Institut (irpp.org/fr).

PubliĂ© sous la direction de David A. Green, W. Craig Riddell et France St-Hilaire, Income Inequality: The Canadian Story, sera le cinquième ouvrage de la collection L’art de l’État de l’IRPP. D’Ă©minents experts y analyseront de nouvelles donnĂ©es sur les causes et effets des inĂ©galitĂ©s croissantes de revenu au Canada, tout en examinant le rĂ´le des politiques publiques en la matière.

-30-

L’Institut de recherche en politiques publiques est un organisme canadien indĂ©pendant, bilingue et sans but lucratif, basĂ© Ă  MontrĂ©al. Pour ĂŞtre tenu au courant de ses activitĂ©s, veuillez vous abonner Ă  son infolettre.

Renseignements :   Shirley Cardenas   tél. : 514 594-6877   scardenas@nullirpp.org

Is new focus on middle class over poverty good for Canadians?

In 1989, the Canadian Parliament passed a resolution to abolish child poverty by 2000. To no one’s surprise, that didn’t happen. Indeed, in recent years, the anti-poverty rhetoric that dominated Canadian policy debates over income distribution has almost disappeared.

In case you haven’t noticed, none of the parties in recent provincial elections have mentioned poverty or the poor very much. As they begin to release their party platforms for the 2015 federal election, all parties have shifted their rhetorical focus to helping “families,” usually vaguely defined as “middle class.” No federal political party is proclaiming a new “war on poverty.”

As two long-time observers of the politics of income distribution in Canada, we find this turnaround stunning. From the late 1960s to the early 2000s, combating poverty entirely dominated not only the rhetoric but also the practices of tax-transfer policy in Canada. Beginning with the Guaranteed Income Supplement for seniors in 1966 and up until 2006 with the Working Income Tax Benefit for low-wage workers, new mechanisms for targeting benefits on those at the bottom were the focus of government innovation.

The shift raises two questions: Why did it happen? And is the shift “good” or “bad” for Canadians? We turn first to the “why” question.

In 2011, the Occupy Movement changed the dial on Canadian debates on income distribution from the “poor” to the “rich” with its focus on the rising incomes of the top one per cent. “Inequality” replaced “poverty” as the hot topic for the pundits and for good reason. Canada is on the leading edge of the 99/1 phenomenon, with the OECD estimating that the top one per cent of Canada’s income earners have captured 37 per cent of total income growth over the past three decades.

While incomes at the top have been rising, conventional poverty measures have been either stable or declining somewhat. Why is that? The answer is simply the flip side of the rising incomes at the top. Statistics Canada’s traditional low-income measures are defined relative to what is happening in the “middle,” and incomes in both the bottom and the middle have been relatively stagnant, both moving in tandem. So poverty rates haven’t changed a lot. The rich have been getting richer, but the poor have not been getting poorer.

The most politically sensitive stresses generated by the growing inequality, however, are found in the middle of the distribution. Indeed, middle-income Canadians are increasingly anxious about their economic prospects, their debt levels, their retirement income and the prospects for their children. Our federal parties are not talking about inequality directly, but they are all advancing policies designed to tap into this growing unease in middle-income Canada.

Federal politics and national-level political parties focus mainly on traditional tax-transfer policies: higher taxes for some, higher benefits or lower taxes for others. That’s because the federal government controls tax and transfer policies. But these provide very limited range in a world where income distribution depends critically on areas like labour market and education policy that are largely under provincial jurisdiction.

Will the reframing of the debate on income distribution be good or bad for those at the bottom? It all depends on the answer Canadians give to the inequality question. Comparative analysts have long argued that “targeting” tax and transfer policies on the “poor” may be economically efficient but politically ineffective. The “poor” are a political minority (now about 13 per cent of the population); they don’t vote much; and have little political influence. Hence, they are the most likely to experience cuts under conditions of fiscal restraint. They are more likely to gain when tax-transfer and other policies include them as part of a much broader range of beneficiaries.

The counterpoint, of course, is the danger that in the new debate about inequality, we lose sight of those at the bottom. Not all policies advanced to help families reflect an egalitarian impulse. Some of them may actually assist upper-income earners more than others and exacerbate inequality.

The struggle to tap into the anxieties generated by growing inequality will be central to the electoral politics of 2015 and could set the direction of social policy in years to come. Much will depend on whether the “middle class” see their interests as aligned with those at the bottom or the top as they prepare to cast their vote.


Keith Banting and John Myles are contributing authors of the forthcoming book Income Inequality: The Canadian Story published by the Institute for Research on Public Policy (irpp.org).

Framing the New Inequality

Autres publications

Économie Inégalités

Articles connexes d’Options politiques

La supercherie des retombées économiques

par Yvan Stringer janvier 24, 2023

Le modèle québécois pour résoudre la pénurie de main-d’œuvre

par Yves Blanchet août 29, 2022

Recherches connexes du Centre d’excellence

The Federal Spending Power in the Trudeau Era: Back to the Future?

par Peter Graefe et Nicole Fiorillo juin 7, 2023

Provincial/Territorial Governments and the Negotiation of International Trade Agreements

par Christopher J. Kukucha octobre 18, 2016